Flickr

  • www.flickr.com
    Abiola_Lapite's photos More of Abiola_Lapite's photos

« Spot the Difference | Main | Hysterical BS »

October 17, 2004

Comments

j

not related to this question, but an observation on (I believe) an underappreciated element of capitalism

the average person I meet in business is much more concerned and dedicated to meeting the needs of others than the average intellectual or artist

it seems that most artists and intellectuals are much more concerned about satisfying their own egos whereas successful businesspeople who build long-term viable enterprises must dedicate themselves to others

i know this is basically expressed in adam smith's invisible hand, but from my experience it is not all that invisible, successful businesspeople really do care about others whereas intellectuals and artists spend most of their time aggrendizing themselves

if anyone has feedback, i would be interested in hearing - thanks

Don Lloyd

Abiola,
Thank you for your interest in my post.

The followup post,
http://catallarchy.net/blog/archives/2004/10/16/choice-of-economies-a-followup/

makes it clearer that I have no interest in omniscient beings, but want to emphasize that the 'figure of merit' of an economy is related to the level and variety of goods and services that are produced and consumed over time and not with any measures of prices. Profits are not only the key to future expansions of consumption, but directly indicate the degree by which the economic value of a final consumer product exceeds the sum of the economic values of its production factors.

Regards, Don


Abiola Lapite

Don,

Thanks for the pointer to your second post. I would like to point out, however, that profits in themselves aren't sufficient to distinguish between free market economies and market socialism of the Lange-Lerner variety, as the latter explicitly envisions state enterprises acting as profit-maximizers; in theory, there is no good reason why total state-ownership should not also lead to a multitude of goods and services calculated to satisfy every possible niche. That this is never so in real life goes without saying, but concentrating on efficiency criteria will not suffice to capture just why there is such a gap between market-socialist theory and practice.

In a nutshell: even if a completely planned market-socialist economy were more (or at least, equally) efficient in the allocation of goods and services in the short and medium term, it would still fall short over the longer term, not because of inefficiencies in its provision of goods and services to meet consumer tastes or because it failed to maximize economic value, given existing technologies, but because it makes no provision for the encouragement of new, unforeseen technologies, and the brand new markets they can give rise to. As such, questions of value-maximization are essentially a red herring; an America utilizing 1904's technologies at a welfare-maximizing level would still be a far poorer place than one utilizing today's techonology in a less than optimal fashion (as I'm certain is actually the case today).

It is with all the above in mind that I found your mention of omniscience problematic, as by ignoring the importance of profits to incentivizing knowledge discovery and exploitation, one throws out the very engine of the prosperity we enjoy presently, and I'll note that despite your mention of entrapreneurs and new ventures, the overwhelming importance of innovation still isn't explicitly addressed in the second post you've made. To clarify the distinction, I offer an example: the Roman Empire had no small number of entrapreneurs and new ventures in its heyday, but the production technologies they employed advanced minimally in the course of hundreds of years, and consequently, so did Roman standards of living, once all the gains to be had from peace, good roads and open borders had been realized.

Julian Elson

This is an interesting question. There are some other things that we need to know about A and B, like:

-How substitutable are different segments with each other? (i.e., does the Coke-and-Pepsi segment face competition not only from each other, but also from orange juice and iced tea?) Higher inter-segment substitution argues for B, since monopolies aren't as damaging within a segment
-Do the firms in these segments know enough about each customer and have enough control over sales to price-discriminate effectively (like colleges), or not? Better price-discrimination argues for B, since monopolies will just tend to lead to a transfer from consumer surplus to producer surplus, not an overall social loss.
-What is the production function like, anyway? Are the benefits of increasing returns big?

Something like, oh, integrated steel production presents a tough case. There are few substitutes (as far as I know), and it'd be tough to price discriminate, since, unlike college admissions, it's a readily transferable commodity, implying one price. So that would seem to argue for A. But the returns to scale are big, so we should do B. This is, of course, exactly what makes market socialism so tempting.

Overall, it seems that, as you said, it's an empirical, a posteriori matter, but not just for the economy as a whole, but for every goshdarn segment of the economy too. Of course, some, like Julian Sanchez, would say that that's dangerous thinking, it invites government micromanagement of the economy when what's really needed are clear principles and transparency, property rights, etc.

Julian Elson

What was Walras's position on this? Something like: "We can have a socialist economy as efficient as a capitalist economy, but only if relative prices and allocations are exactly the same, so you have the same inequalities, but with the nasty government screwing the workers instead of the nasty capitalists." Or something like that?

Abiola Lapite

"Of course, some, like Julian Sanchez, would say that that's dangerous thinking, it invites government micromanagement of the economy when what's really needed are clear principles and transparency, property rights, etc."

I share that bias myself, but where I differ from most libertarians is in acknowledging that it is a bias, and that one can't rule out a priori the necessity of at least some government intervention.

Even if anti-trust were to be abolished, there'd still be the patent system, trademarks, copyrights and other government-enforced measures in place acting to protect the profits of innovators, so we'd hardly be looking at a "pure" free market in any case, and I find it extremely hard to believe that a system without any safeguards to ensure that innovators capture at least some of the benefits of their ideas would lead to the sort of prosperity we enjoy today. The examples of ancient civilizations like Rome and China, which had well developed travel networks, high literacy, sophisticated merchant classes, etc, and yet which never managed to make the leap unto the high-growth path the West has been on over the last 200 years, certainly argues against the notion that a society without at least a few government-backed incentives for innovators will be a high-growth one.

In short, I think what exactly constitutes "property rights" is a fundamental problem that is simply assumed away by most standard libertarian boilerplate.

"What was Walras's position on this?"

I don't know offhand, but I'll take a look later in the day and see if my copy of Blaug's "History of Economic Thought" has anything to say about this.

Don Lloyd

Abiola,

My use of 'omniscient being' was merely an attempt to indicate that no individual or group can possibly have access to enough information to make a comparison of different economies. My only interest in optimization is that pursued by individuals and individual firms in their own interest.

My follow-up post preceded in time your reference, so innovation was not mentioned explicitly, although it cetainly is a major part of entrepreurship.

Monopolies, in the unpriviliged single-supplier sense, sometimes emerge as the result of individual firms acting to maximize their own profits over time, and are not to be feared or impeded. As long as monopolies are maintained by satisfying consumers in price, variety and quality, as opposed to physical threats, they are entirely appropriate, and not necessarily permanent.

I find the entire idea of 'consumer surplus' as generally useless, as the price that a consumer is willing to pay for a given good is extremely unstable and path dependent. It also seems strange to use a measure that highly overweights the Bill Gates of the world whose time opportunity costs prevent even just the amount of thought required to form an opinion of a price for most goods.

My point overall is that prices are an allocation tool and a signal, not a collective value measure.

Regards, Don

gene berman

All of you guys find a particular tree and "bark up it." And, in so doing, the particular tree that hasn't been barked up but has been pissed on by neglect is the most important of all: some method for determining the composite valuation of future goods as against those in the present. No other method than that furnished by a private market for the real things comprehended in the words "tools of production" and a capital market which produces loan prices (to include not only the presently prevailing discount of future goods but also ineradicable riskiness arising from the intended project itself) can possibly enable a director to determine the magnitude called "costs." The mere allocation of raw materials and labor to the production of specific goods chosen on some basis that seems rational to the director is only a small part of the total problem. Thwere are matters to be considered having to do with whether to construct large machines which will operate at the highest capacity possible or many smaller machines

gene berman

shit--posted accidentally before finishing. But that's OK--you get the idea.

gene berman

It should also be noted that only by making the comparisons referred to can the "director" establish whether or not the project is proceeding properly, whether it is not (i.e., incurring losses) and to what extent and at what rate such capital must be replaced (to avoid consumption of the "seed corn"). I'd say "back to the drawing board," except that's the wrong place to solve the problem posed.

The comments to this entry are closed.

Notes for Readers